Fed policy, the Sahm rule and the risk of recession

Rising unemployment has almost reached the "Sahm rule" threshold that has historically been a useful guide to US recessions.
Kieran Davies

Coolabah Capital

Policy rules point to lower rates as inflation slowly returns to target, where a materially higher unemployment rate would demand faster action given the Fed currently forecasts little change in unemployment. Unemployment of just over 4% has almost triggered the Sahm rule threshold for recession, a rule-of-thumb that captures the post-WW2 experience of every sharp rise in US unemployment being driven by the job losses that are the hallmark of recession. The Fed responds forcefully to recessions, although the rise in unemployment to date has been driven more by employment failing to keep pace with the expanding workforce rather than broad job losses.

Over the past couple of years, the US economy has held up much better than either economists or the Fed had expected, contradicting the long-running signal from the earlier inversion of the yield curve that a recession was highly likely any time from H2 2023 through 2024.

One explanation for this resilience is that the neutral policy rate – or at least the short-run version of neutral – has increased from its pre-pandemic lows, perhaps because of shocks to the economy like continued easy fiscal policy, something that is supported by market pricing and Fed modelling.

Another explanation is that the overhang from COVID was longer than anticipated, drawing out the already long and variable lags of monetary policy. For example, job vacancies have only recently broadly returned to pre-pandemic levels, raising the possibility that a further material decline in vacancies could finally be reflected in a sharp rise in the unemployment rate.

These two explanations are not mutually exclusive. It may be that high interest rates are finally slowing the economy, but that a higher neutral rate means that average interest rates are likely to be higher than pre-pandemic levels for some time.

Recently, the unemployment rate has started to signal an increased risk that the US could finally enter recession, increasing from a multi-decade level of about 3½% last year to just over 4%. 

At this level, the unemployment rate signals that the labour market is broadly back in balance, matching economist and Fed estimates of the NAIRU that range between 4-4¼% (the Congressional Budget Office estimate of the NAIRU is a little higher at almost 4½%).   

The
US job vacancy rate is broadly back at pre-COVID levels and the higher
unemployment rate is broadly in line with most estimates of the NAIRU 
The US job vacancy rate is broadly back at pre-COVID levels and the higher unemployment rate is broadly in line with most estimates of the NAIRU 

The rise in unemployment has almost triggered the 0.5pp threshold signifying the start of a recession in the “Sahm rule”, with the average unemployment rate over the past three months now 0.4pp higher than its low point over the past year (a probit model based on the Sahm rule would equate a 0.4pp reading with a 10% risk of recession, with the rule’s 0.5pp threshold met if the unemployment rate soon rose to 4.3% or more).  

The
rise in the US unemployment rate has seen the Sahm rule indicator pick up
The rise in the US unemployment rate has seen the Sahm rule indicator pick up

The Sahm rule of thumb is not precise, mainly because using the change in the three-month average of the unemployment rate introduces some inertia into the calculation, and there is no guarantee that it will continue to hold in the future.

Nonetheless, it does better than any other economic indicator in providing a timely signal of recession. 

This reliability reflects the fact that every sharp rise in the US unemployment rate in the post-WW2 period has been driven by the job losses that are the hallmark of a recession.

(“Soft landings” – which are the rare instances when the Fed has tightened policy without triggering a recession – are a different matter, with unemployment falling during the three soft landings of the 1960s, 1980s and 1990s.)

Unemployment
has been a reliable indicator of recession in the US because sharp rises in
unemployment have reflected job losses 
Unemployment has been a reliable indicator of recession in the US because sharp rises in unemployment have reflected job losses 

The recent rise in the unemployment rate has reflected weakness in employment. Employment is volatile, but has edged lower in trend terms over recent months and is broadly unchanged from the level of a year ago.

A natural reaction would be to downplay this weakness because it contrasts with the less volatile number of payroll jobs, which have continued to grow, albeit at a slower rate. 

Payrolls are broader in scope and less volatile than surveyed employment, counting, for instance, the additional jobs worked by some people. They are derived from a separate survey of business and have traditionally been the Fed’s preferred measure of the demand for labour.

However, it seems likely that the unusual divergence between employment and payrolls will eventually be resolved by an upward revision to employment and a downward revision to payrolls.

Employment appears understated because the population benchmarks used to construct employment do not fully capture the recent surge in migration (broadly speaking, employment is estimated by multiplying the ratio of employment to population from a sample of households by population benchmarks).

As a recent analysis by the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas shows, the surge in international migration estimated by the CBO over the past couple of years – where more illegal migrants have been released into the community – is yet to be reflected in census data on the population.

Nevertheless, even if the level of employment is eventually revised higher, recent growth will likely still be relatively weak given the sample estimates of the ratio of employment to the population should be less affected by the jump in migration.

Payrolls seem biased in the other direction, with more comprehensive, but less timely payroll estimates sourced from unemployment insurance data posting slower growth over last year.    

The
level of surveyed employment will likely eventually be revised higher, while
the headline measure of payroll jobs will probably be revised lower 
The level of surveyed employment will likely eventually be revised higher, while the headline measure of payroll jobs will probably be revised lower 
Adjusting
for higher migration would boost the estimated level of employment, but
recent growth would probably still be weak 
Adjusting for higher migration would boost the estimated level of employment, but recent growth would probably still be weak 

For the Fed, a further material rise in unemployment would pressure policy-makers to cut interest rates.

Most policy rules incorporate both the expected inflation rate and the anticipated gap between the unemployment rate and the NAIRU, pointing to lower interest rates assuming inflation returns to target over the next couple of years.

Meaningfully higher unemployment would point to a faster decline in interest rates given the FOMC currently forecasts this gap will be broadly in balance over the next few years, with the unemployment rate expected to fluctuate between 4 and 4.2%.

The extent of the pressure on rates would also likely depend on what drove unemployment rate higher. If it reflected the usual job losses seen in a recession, history shows the Fed would respond forcefully in cutting rates.

Alternatively, the Fed might be more cautious in cutting rates if higher unemployment reflected employment failing to keep pace with growth in the workforce, which explains most of the increase in unemployment to date. 

Such an outcome would be unprecedented for the US in the post-WW2 period, although it is a common occurrence in other advanced economies, such as the euro area and Australia.   

As
you would expect, the Fed cuts rates more aggressively in recessions than “soft
landings”
As you would expect, the Fed cuts rates more aggressively in recessions than “soft landings”
........
Investment Disclaimer Past performance does not assure future returns. All investments carry risks, including that the value of investments may vary, future returns may differ from past returns, and that your capital is not guaranteed. This information has been prepared by Coolabah Capital Investments Pty Ltd (ACN 153 327 872). It is general information only and is not intended to provide you with financial advice. You should not rely on any information herein in making any investment decisions. To the extent permitted by law, no liability is accepted for any loss or damage as a result of any reliance on this information. The Product Disclosure Statement (PDS) for the funds should be considered before deciding whether to acquire or hold units in it. A PDS for these products can be obtained by visiting www.coolabahcapital.com. Neither Coolabah Capital Investments Pty Ltd, Equity Trustees Ltd (ACN 004 031 298) nor their respective shareholders, directors and associated businesses assume any liability to investors in connection with any investment in the funds, or guarantees the performance of any obligations to investors, the performance of the funds or any particular rate of return. The repayment of capital is not guaranteed. Investments in the funds are not deposits or liabilities of any of the above-mentioned parties, nor of any Authorised Deposit-taking Institution. The funds are subject to investment risks, which could include delays in repayment and/or loss of income and capital invested. Past performance is not an indicator of nor assures any future returns or risks. Coolabah Capital Investments (Retail) Pty Limited (CCIR) (ACN 153 555 867) is an authorised representative (#000414337) of Coolabah Capital Institutional Investments Pty Ltd (CCII) (AFSL 482238). Both CCIR and CCII are wholly owned subsidiaries of Coolabah Capital Investments Pty Ltd. Equity Trustees Ltd (AFSL 240975) is the Responsible Entity for these funds. Equity Trustees Ltd is a subsidiary of EQT Holdings Limited (ACN 607 797 615), a publicly listed company on the Australian Securities Exchange (ASX: EQT). Forward-Looking Disclaimer This presentation contains some forward-looking information. These statements are not guarantees of future performance and undue reliance should not be placed on them. Such forward-looking statements necessarily involve known and unknown risks and uncertainties, which may cause actual performance and financial results in future periods to differ materially from any projections of future performance or result expressed or implied by such forward-looking statements. Although forward-looking statements contained in this presentation are based upon what Coolabah Capital Investments Pty Ltd believes are reasonable assumptions, there can be no assurance that forward-looking statements will prove to be accurate, as actual results and future events could differ materially from those anticipated in such statements. Coolabah Capital Investments Pty Ltd undertakes no obligation to update forward-looking statements if circumstances or management’s estimates or opinions should change except as required by applicable securities laws. The reader is cautioned not to place undue reliance on forward-looking statements.

Kieran Davies
Chief Macro Strategist
Coolabah Capital

Based in Sydney, Kieran Davies is Chief Macro Strategist at Coolabah Capital Investments, an asset manager with 40 executives and over $8 billion in fixed-income strategies. Kieran is responsible for macroeconomic research and investment strategy,...

I would like to

Only to be used for sending genuine email enquiries to the Contributor. Livewire Markets Pty Ltd reserves its right to take any legal or other appropriate action in relation to misuse of this service.

Personal Information Collection Statement
Your personal information will be passed to the Contributor and/or its authorised service provider to assist the Contributor to contact you about your investment enquiry. They are required not to use your information for any other purpose. Our privacy policy explains how we store personal information and how you may access, correct or complain about the handling of personal information.

Comments

Sign In or Join Free to comment